ディスクロージャー研究学会



(青空に物事を晒すと虫干しされ綺麗になる)

文書No.
700801e

THE MARKET FOR "LEMONS"

    :QUALITY UNCERTAINTY AND THE MARKET MECHANISM *

    GEORGE A. AKERLOF QUARTALY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS 1970   T.Introduction 488.- U.The model with automobiles as an example 489.- V. Examples and applications 492.- W.Counteracting institutions 499.- X.Conclusion 500.  

T.INTRODUCTION

 This paper relates quality and uncertainty. The existence of goods of

 many grades poses interesting and important problems for the theory

ofmarkets. On theone hand
 the interaction of quality differences and

 uncertainty may explain im-portant institutions of the labor market. On the

other hand
 this paper presentsa struggling attempt to give structure to

 the statement: "Business in underde- veloped countries is difficult"; in

particular
 a structure is given for deter- mining the economic costs of

 dishonesty. Additional applications of the theory include comments on the

structure of money markets
on thenotion of "insurabili-ty
on the
liquidity of durables
 and on brand-name goods. There are many mar- kets in

 which buyers use some market statistic to judge the quality of prospec-

 tive purchases. In this case there is incentive for sellers to market poor

qual-ity merchandise
 since the returns for good quality accrue mainly to

 the entire group whose statistic is affected rather than to the individual

 seller. As a re-sult there tends to be a reduction in the average quality

 of goods and also in the size of the market. It should also be perceived

 that in these markets socialand private returns differ

and therefore
in
some cases
 governmental interven-tion may increase the welfare of all

 parties. Or private institutions may arise to take advantage of the

 potential increases the welfare of all parties. Or pri-vate institutions

 may arise to take advantage of the potential increases in wel-fare which

can accrue to all parties. By nature
however
these institutions
arenonatomistic
 and therefore concentrations of power−with ill

 consequences of their own−can develop.


 *The author would especially like to thank Thomas Rothenberg for

 invaluable comments and inspiration. In addition he is indebted to Roy

Radner
Albert Fishlow
Bernard Saffran
William D. Nordhaus
Giorgio
LaMalfa
Charles C.Holt
John Letiche
and the referee for help and
 suggestions. He would also like to thank the Indian statistical Institute

 and the Ford Foundation for financial support.


 The automobile market is used as a finger exercise to illustrate and

 developthese thoughts. It should be emphasized that this market is chosen

 for its con- creteness and ease in understanding rather than for its

importance or realism.


 U.THE MODEL WITH AUTOMOBILES AS AN EXAMPLE

A.The Automobiles Market
 The example of used cars captures the essence of the problem.From time to

 time one hears either mention of or surprise at the large price difference

 be- tween new cars and those which have just left the showroom. The usual

 lunch ta- ble justification for this phenomenon is the pure joy of owing a


 new" car. We offer a different explanation. Suppose (for the sake of

 clarity rather than re- ality) that there are just four kinds of cars.

 There are new cars and used cars.There are good cars and bad cars(which in

 America are known as "lemons"). A new car may be a good car or a lemon

and
 of course the same is true of used cars.

 The individuals in this market buy a new automobile without knowing

 whether the car they buy will be good or a lemon. But they do know that

 with probabilityq it is a good car and with probability(1−q) it is a

lemon; by assumption
 q isthe proportion of good cars produced and (1−q)

 is the proportion of lemons. Af-ter owning a specific car

however
for a
length of time
 the car owner canform a good idea of the quality of this

machine; i.e.
 the owner assigns a new proba-bility to the event that his

 car is a lemon. This estimate is more accurate thanthe original estimate.

 An asymmetry in available information has developed: for the sellers now

 have more knowledge about the quality of a car than the buyers. But good

 cars and bad cars must still sell at the same price−sinceit is impos-

 sible for a buyer to tell the difference between a good car and a bad car.

 It isapparent that a used car cannot have the same valuation as a new

car−if it did have the same valuation
it would clearly be advantageous to
 trade a lemon at the price of new car

and buy another new car
at a
 higher probability q of be- ing good and a lower probability of being bad.

 Thus the owner of a good machine must be locked in. Not only is it true

 that he cannot receive the true value of his car

but he cannot even obtain
the expected value of a new car.
 Gresham's law has made a modifide reappearance. For most cars traded will

be the "lemons
 and good cars may not be traded at all. The

bad" cars
 tend to drive out the good (in much the same way that bad money drives

 out the good). But the analogy with Gresham's law is not quite complete:

 bad cars drive out thegood because they sell at the same price as good

cars; similarly
 bad money drives out good because the exchange rate is

 even. But the bad cars sell at the same price as good cars since it is

 impossible for a buyer to tell the differ- ence between a good and a bad

 car; only the seller knows. In Gresham's law

how-ever
presumably both
 buyer and seller can tell the difference between good and bad money. So

the analogy is instructive
but not complete.


お問い合わせ ik8m-ysmr@asahi-net.or.jp


目次に戻る